definição e significado de tariff | sensagent.com


   Publicitade E▼


 » 
alemão búlgaro chinês croata dinamarquês eslovaco esloveno espanhol estoniano farsi finlandês francês grego hebraico hindi holandês húngaro indonésio inglês islandês italiano japonês korean letão língua árabe lituano malgaxe norueguês polonês português romeno russo sérvio sueco tailandês tcheco turco vietnamês
alemão búlgaro chinês croata dinamarquês eslovaco esloveno espanhol estoniano farsi finlandês francês grego hebraico hindi holandês húngaro indonésio inglês islandês italiano japonês korean letão língua árabe lituano malgaxe norueguês polonês português romeno russo sérvio sueco tailandês tcheco turco vietnamês

Definição e significado de tariff

Definição

tariff (n.)

1.a listing of prices for different goods or services

2.a government tax on imports or exports"they signed a treaty to lower duties on trade between their countries"

tariff (v.)

1.charge a tariff"tariff imported goods"

   Publicidade ▼

Merriam Webster

TariffTar"iff (?), n. [F. tarif; cf. Sp. & Pg. tarifa, It. tariffa; all fr. Ar. ta'rīf information, explanation, definition, from 'arafa, to know, to inform, explain.]
1. A schedule, system, or scheme of duties imposed by the government of a country upon goods imported or exported; as, a revenue tariff; a protective tariff; Clay's compromise tariff. (U. S. 1833).

☞ The United States and Great Britain impose no duties on exports; hence, in these countries the tariff refers only to imports.

☞ A tariff may be imposed solely for, and with reference to, the production of revenue (called a revenue tariff, or tariff for revenue, or for the artificial fostering of home industries (a projective tariff), or as a means of coercing foreign governments, as in case of retaliatory tariff.

2. The duty, or rate of duty, so imposed; as, the tariff on wool; a tariff of two cents a pound.

3. Any schedule or system of rates, changes, etc.; as, a tariff of fees, or of railroad fares. Bolingbroke.

TariffTar"iff, v. t. [imp. & p. p. Tariffed (?); p. pr. & vb. n. Tariffing.] To make a list of duties on, as goods.

   Publicidade ▼

Definiciones (más)

definição - Wikipedia

Sinónimos

Locuções

2002 United States steel tariff • Airline Tariff Publishing Company • Availability based tariff • Bound tariff rate • Cayley-Galt Tariff • Common external tariff • Constitutional tariff • Customs tariff • Dallas tariff • Differential tariff • Dingley Tariff • Domestic tariff area • Drug Tariff • Electricity tariff • Emergency Tariff of 1921 • Environmental tariff • Feed-in tariff • Fordney–McCumber Tariff • Hamilton tariff • Harmonized Tariff Schedule for the United States • Hoot Smalley Tariff • Hoot-Smalley Tariff • Immigration tariff • McKinley Tariff • Mongrel Tariff • Morrill Tariff • Munich Transport and Tariff Association • National Tariff System • Non-tariff barrier • Non-tariff barriers • Non-tariff barriers to trade • Non-tariff trade barrier • Payne–Aldrich Tariff Act • Protective tariff • Reciprocal Tariff Act • Revenue Tariff Party • Russian Customs Tariff • Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act • Tariff (disambiguation) • Tariff Act of 1789 • Tariff Commission Building • Tariff Reform League • Tariff of 1789 • Tariff of 1790 • Tariff of 1792 • Tariff of 1824 • Tariff of 1828 • Tariff of 1832 • Tariff of 1833 • Tariff of 1842 • Tariff of 1846 • Tariff of 1857 • Tariff of 1883 • Tariff reform • Tariff-rate quota • Tax, tariff and trade • Tax, tariff, and trade • Tax, trade, and tariff • Tax, trade, tariff • Telecommunications tariff • Trade and Tariff Act of 1984 • Two-part tariff • UCAS Tariff • Walker tariff • Wilson–Gorman Tariff Act

Dicionario analógico

tariff (n.)


tariff (n.)

impôt douanier (fr)[ClasseHyper.]

indirect tax[Hyper.]

tariff[Dérivé]


tariff (v.)


Wikipedia

Tariff

                   

A tariff is either (1) a tax on imports or exports (trade tariff) in and out of a country, or (2) a list or schedule of prices for such things as rail service, bus routes, and electrical usage (electrical tariff, etc.).[1]

Contents

  Etymology

The word comes from the Italian word tariffa "list of prices, book of rates," which is derived from the Arabic ta'rif "to notify or announce."[2]

  Trade tariffs in the United States

Tariffs, often called customs, were by far the largest source of United States federal revenue from the 1790s to the eve of World War I, when they were surpassed by income taxes.

  Economic analysis

Neoclassical economic theorists tend to view tariffs as distortions to the free market. Typical analyses find that tariffs tend to benefit domestic producers and government at the expense of consumers, and that the net welfare effects of a tariff on the importing country are negative. Normative judgments often follow from these findings, namely that it may be disadvantageous for a country to artificially shield an industry from world markets, and that it might be better to allow a collapse to take place. Opposition to all tariffs is part of the free trade principle; the World Trade Organization aims to reduce tariffs and to avoid countries discriminating between differing countries when applying tariffs.

Tariff.JPG

The diagram to the right shows the costs and benefits of imposing a tariff on a good in the domestic economy, Home.

When incorporating free international trade into the model we use a supply curve denoted as Pw. This curve makes the assumption that the international supply of the good or service is perfectly elastic and that the world can produce at a near infinite quantity at the given price. Obviously, in real world conditions this is somewhat unrealistic, but making such assumptions is unlikely to have a material impact on the outcome of the model.

At world equilibrium, Pw, Home produced only S amount of the good, but had a demand of D. The difference between S and D, SD was filled by importing from abroad. After the imposition of tariff, domestic price rises from Pw to Pt but foreign export prices fall from Pw to Pt* due to the difference in tax incidence on the consumers (at home) and producers (abroad).

At the new price level at Home, Pt, which is higher than the previous Pw, more of the good is produced at Home – it now makes S* of the good. Due to the higher price, only D* of the good is demanded by Home. The difference between S* and D*, S*D* is filled by importing from abroad. Thus, imposition of tariffs reduce the quantity of imports from SD to S*D*.

Domestic producers enjoy a gain in their surplus. Producer surplus, defined as the difference between what the producers were willing to receive by selling a good and the actual price of the good, expands from the region below Pw to the region below Pt. Therefore, the domestic producers gain an amount shown by the area A.

Domestic consumers face a higher price, reducing their welfare. Consumer surplus is the area between the price line and the demand curve. Therefore, the consumer surplus shrinks from the area above Pw to the area above Pt, i.e. it shrinks by the areas A, B, C and D.

The government gains from the tariffs. It charges an amount PtPt* of tariff for every good imported. Since S*D* goods are imported, the government gains an area of C and E.


The net loss to the society due to the tariff would be given by the total costs of the tariff minus its benefits to the society. Therefore, we can conclude that the net welfare loss due to the tariff is equal to:

Consumer Loss – Government revenue – Producer gain

or graphically, this gain is given by the areas shown by:

(A + B + C + D) – (C + E) – A
= B + D – E

that is, tariffs are beneficial to the society if the area given by the rectangle E more than offsets the losses shown by triangles B and D. Rectangle E is called the terms of trade gain whereas the two triangles B and D are also called efficiency loss, as this cost is incurred because tariffs reduce the incentives for the society to consume and produce.

The model above is only completely accurate in the extreme case where none of the consumers belong to the producers group and the cost of the product is a fraction of their wages. If instead, we take the opposite extreme, and assume all consumers come from the producers' group, and also assume their only purchasing power comes from the wages earned in production and the product costs their whole wage, then the graph looks radically different. Without tariffs, only those producers/consumers able to produce the product at the world price will have the money to purchase it at that price.

Note also, that with or without tariffs, there is no incentive to buy the imported goods over the domestic, as the price of each is the same. Only by altering available purchasing power through debt, selling off assets, or new wages from new forms of domestic production, will the imported goods be purchased. Or, of course, if its price were only a fraction of wages.[citation needed]

In the real world, as more imports replace domestic goods, they consume a larger fraction of available domestic wages, moving the graph towards this view of the model. If new forms of production are not found in time, the nation will go bankrupt, and internal political pressures will lead to debt default, extreme tariffs, or worse.[citation needed]

Establishing tariffs inefficiently slows down this process at the expense of the consumer's real wages, allowing more time for new forms of production to be developed, but also buttresses industries which may never regain competitive prices.[citation needed]

  Political analysis

The tariff has been used as a political tool to establish an independent nation; for example, the United States Tariff Act of 1789, signed specifically on July 4, was called the "Second Declaration of Independence" by newspapers because it was intended to be the economic means to achieve the political goal of a sovereign and independent United States.[3]

In modern times, the political impact of tariffs has been seen in a positive and negative sense. The 2002 United States steel tariff imposed a 30% tariff on a variety of imported steel products for a period of three years. American steel producers supported the tariff,[4] but the move was criticised by the Cato Institute.[5]

Tariffs can occasionally emerge as a political issue prior to an election. In the leadup to the 2007 Australian Federal election, the Australian Labor Party announced it would undertake a review of Australian car tariffs if elected.[6] The Liberal Party made a similar commitment, while independent candidate Nick Xenophon announced his intention to introduce tariff-based legislation as "a matter of urgency".[7]

  Tariffs within technology strategies

When tariffs are an integral element of a country's technology strategy, the tariffs can be highly effective in helping to increase and maintain the country's economic health. As an integral part of the technology strategy, tariffs are effective in supporting the technology strategy's function of enabling the country to out maneuver the competition in the acquisition and utilization of technology in order to produce products and provide services that excel at satisfying the customer needs for a competitive advantage in domestic and foreign markets.

In contrast, in economic theory tariffs are viewed as a primary element in international trade with the function of the tariff being to influence the flow of trade by lowering or raising the price of targeted goods to create what amounts to an artificial competitive advantage. When tariffs are viewed and used in this fashion, they are addressing the country's and the competitors' respective economic healths in terms of maximizing or minimizing revenue flow rather than in terms of the ability to generate and maintain a competitive advantage which is the source of the revenue. As a result, the impact of the tariffs on the economic health of the country are at best minimal but often are counter-productive.

A program within the US intelligence community, Project Socrates, that was tasked with addressing America's declining economic competitiveness, determined that countries like China and India were using tariffs as an integral element of their respective technology strategies to rapidly build their countries into economic superpowers. It was also determined that the US, in its early years, had also used tariffs as an integral part of what amounted to technology strategies to transform the country into a superpower.[8]

  See also

Types of tariff:

Trade dynamics:

Trade liberalisation:

General:

  References

  1. ^ India. Brihan Mumbai Electric Supply & Transport Undertaking; Tariff Booklet. Mumbai: The Maharashtra Electricity Regulatory Commission, 2009. Web. 14 Jul 2011. <http://bestundertaking.com/pdf/Tariff_Schedule.pdf>.
  2. ^ The Online Etymology Dictionary: tariff. The 2nd edition of the Oxford English Dictionary gives the same etymology, with a reference dating to 1591
  3. ^ "Thomas Jefferson - under George Washington by America's History". americashistory.org. http://americashistory.org/detail.aspx?cat=12&man=452. 
  4. ^ "Behind the Steel-Tariff Curtain". March 8, 2002. http://www.businessweek.com/bwdaily/dnflash/mar2002/nf2002038_1478.htm. 
  5. ^ "Trade Briefing Paper no. 14. Steel Trap: How Subsidies and Protectionism Weaken the U.S. Steel Industry". Cato's Center for Trade Policy Studies. http://www.freetrade.org/node/27. 
  6. ^ Sid Marris and Dennis Shanahan (November 9, 2007). "PM rulses out more help for car firms". The Australian. http://www.theaustralian.news.com.au/story/0,25197,22729573-5013871,00.html. 
  7. ^ "Candidate wants car tariff cuts halted". Melbourne: theage.com.au. October 29, 2007. http://www.theage.com.au/news/National/Candidate-wants-car-tariff-cuts-halted/2007/10/29/1193618771259.html. 
  8. ^ Watts, Denise K. (1990-06-28). "Martin County News". Gathering Information on High Technology. 

  Further reading

  External links

   
               

 

todas as traduções do tariff


Conteùdo de sensagent

  • definição
  • sinónimos
  • antónimos
  • enciclopédia

 

4732 visitantes em linha

calculado em 0,032s